Paul
Goble
Staunton, October 12 – The imposition
of new rules prohibiting the sharing of statistical information among various
levels of Russian government and the continuing impact of Soviet assumptions
that individuals only work where they live mean that 33 to 37 percent of the
population of Russian regions is “invisible” as far as state statistics are
concerned.
That conclusion, offered by Simon
Kordonsky of the Khamovniki Foundation and three other sociologists, means that
Moscow “does not see the real life of the provinces” and continues to make decisions
and allocate funds on the basis of what appears to be increasingly inaccurate
information (tvrain.ru/articles/hamovniki-396045/).
In the 1990s, they report,
municipalities gathered most economic and demographic statistics. Then after 2000,
three things happened: Federal agencies began to take over, statistical staffs
were cut, and by 2005, Moscow prohibited the sharing of information among local
governments, the tax service and Rosstat.
Such sharing helped to correct
mistakes by one agency or another, but now that safety value has been shut
down. Indeed, the only administrations that have more or less reliable
information are those who ignore this administrative measure and openly violate
the law, the sociologists say.
As a result, the authorities “look
at real life” only on the basis of the data they are given without much regard
to how accurate it is. And as a result, they make decisions which they might
not make if they had accurate data about realities. Moreover, this approach
leads to significant undercounts on many indices.
In Russia’s provinces, the
sociologists say, “approximately 33 to 37 percent of the active population is invisible
for state statistics” and hence for government officials. The reason, they say,
is that many mid-sized Russian cities now live in “the so-called ‘garage
economy,’” in which people live in one district but work in another or in the
shadow economy.
In the garages of some cities, “sometimes
more people work” in these spheres, including in sectors that should be
classified as industrial production, than do in the official local
economy. In Toliatti, the sociologists
point out, there are more people involved in “the garage economy” than in the
city’s major official employer, AvtoVAZ.
To a certain extent, they say, “the
percent of such enterprises has remained practically unchanged from tsarist
times,” but the measurement of them has. “Consumer cooperatives did not
disappear after they were banned in 1956, and from that moment began the growth
of the shadow sector.”
“If the traditional economy exists
in a system of institutions,” Kordonsky and his colleagues say, “the garage
economy does not fit into this system. Registration is necessary only if it is
required to avoid interference” with the economic activity of these “firms,”
and that is hardly always the case.
The sociologists give another
example of this kind of economic activity which is now uncounted by the state. “Almost
40 percent of the population of Russia uses the resources of the forests in a
way uncontrolled by the state.” Most people think this is about mushroom
hunting or gathering of firewood, but it often involves far larger and more lucrative
activities which are not being counted.
People at the local level know what
is going on, but they no longer have to report it. Most people don’t want to
share the information with those higher up because they may be involved as well. But what this signifies, the sociologists
say, is “the formation of a corporative state” in which many people are active
at one level without officials at another knowing about it.
No comments:
Post a Comment